Tuesday, May 28, 2013


Disruptions: The Real Hazards of E-Devices on Planes

By NICK BILTON





Over the last year, flying with phones and other devices has become increasingly dangerous.
In September, a passenger was arrested in El Paso after refusing to turn off his cellphone as the plane was landing. In October, a man in Chicago was arrested because he used his iPad during takeoff. In November, half a dozen police cars raced across the tarmac at La Guardia Airport in New York, surrounding a plane as if there were a terrorist on board. They arrested a 30-year-old man who had also refused to turn off his phone while on the runway.
Who is to blame in these episodes? You can’t solely pin it on the passengers. Some of the responsibility falls on the Federal Aviation Administration, for continuing to uphold a rule that is based on the unproven idea that a phone or tablet can interfere with the operation of a plane.
These conflicts have been going on for several years. In 2010, a 68-year-old man punched a teenager because he didn’t turn off his phone. Lt. Kent Lipple of the Boise Police Department in Idaho, who arrested the puncher, said the man “felt he was protecting the entire plane and its occupants.” And let’s not forget Alec Baldwin, who was kicked off an American Airlines plane in 2011 for playing Words With Friends online while parked at the gate.
Dealing with the F.A.A. on this topic is like arguing with a stubborn teenager. The agency has no proof that electronic devices can harm a plane’s avionics, but it still perpetuates such claims, spreading irrational fear among millions of fliers.
A year ago, when I first asked Les Dorr, a spokesman for the F.A.A., why the rule existed, he said the agency was being cautious because there was no proof that device use was completely safe. He also said it was because passengers needed to pay attention during takeoff.
When I asked why I can read a printed book but not a digital one, the agency changed its reasoning. I was told by another F.A.A. representative that it was because an iPad or Kindle could put out enough electromagnetic emissions to disrupt the flight. Yet a few weeks later, the F.A.A. proudly announced that pilots could now use iPads in the cockpit instead of paper flight manuals.
The F.A.A. then told me that “two iPads are very different than 200.” But experts at EMT Labs, an independent testing facility in Mountain View, Calif., say there is no difference in radio output between two iPads and 200. “Electromagnetic energy doesn’t add up like that,” said Kevin Bothmann, the EMT Labs testing manager.
It’s not a matter of a flying device hitting another passenger, either. Kindles weigh less than six ounces; Walter Isaacson’s biography of Steve Jobs weighs 2.1 pounds in hardcover. I’d rather be hit in the head by an iPad Mini than a 650-page book.
In October, after months of pressure from the public and the news media, the F.A.A. finally said it would begin a review of its policies on electronic devices in all phases of flight, including takeoff and landing. But the agency does not have a set time frame for announcing its findings.
An F.A.A. spokeswoman told me last week that the agency was preparing to move to the next phase of its work in this area, and would appoint members to a rule-making committee that will begin meeting in January.
The F.A.A. should check out an annual report issued by NASA that compiles cases involving electronic devices on planes. None of those episodes have produced scientific evidence that a device can harm a plane’s operation. Reports of such interference have been purely speculation by pilots about the cause of a problem.
Other government agencies and elected officials are finally getting involved.
This December, Julius Genachowski, chairman of the Federal Communications Commission, sent a letter to the F.A.A. telling the agency that it had a responsibility to “enable greater use of tablets, e-readers and other portable devices” during flights, as they empower people and allow “both large and small businesses to be more productive and efficient, helping drive economic growth and boost U.S. competitiveness.”
A week later, Senator Claire McCaskill, Democrat of Missouri, also sent a letter to the F.A.A. noting that the public was “growing increasingly skeptical of prohibitions” on devices on airplanes. She warned that she was “prepared to pursue legislative solutions should progress be made too slowly.”
If progress is slow, there will eventually be an episode on a plane in which someone is seriously harmed as a result of a device being on during takeoff. But it won’t be because the device is interfering with the plane’s systems. Instead, it will be because one passenger harms another, believing they are protecting the plane from a Kindle, which produces fewer electromagnetic emissions than a calculator.
E-mail: bilton@nytimes.com
A version of this article appeared in print on 12/31/2012, on page B5 of the NewYork edition with the headline: The Real Hazards Of E-Devices on Planes.

The (absence of) political support for the estate tax

I have started working on the (absence of) political support for estate taxation, and I have come across this entry into Paul Krugman's blog.


The Heritage Heritage

A blast from the past: the first time I spent a lot of time dredging through Heritage Foundation “analyses” was when I was writing this 2002 piece on inequality. And I was particularly struck by the Heritage work on the estate tax (pdf), which contained passages like this:
Every day, social and economic decisions are made with the estate tax in mind. Minority businesspeople suffer anxious moments wondering whether the businesses they hope to hand to down to their children will be destroyed by the estate tax bill. Factories drone on with worn-out equipment that would be replaced if capital costs fell. Women who have raised their children struggle to find ways to re-enter the work force without upsetting the family’s estate tax avoidance plan.
What do these examples have in common? They almost never happen. Very few people pay any estate tax at all; very few small businesses were worth enough to pay the estate tax, let alone face breakup because of taxes, even at 2000 levels.
Also note the phony macroeconomic estimates in the Heritage document, with vast job losses from the estate tax — something I don’t think any serious economist would consider plausible.
And yes, William Beach, who wrote that ludicrous death tax piece, also did the vanishing 2.8 percent unemployment piece for Ryan. He’s what Heritage considers an expert.

Monday, May 20, 2013

Lane Kenworthy's proposal for early education

Lane Kenworthy's compelling argument in favor of publicly financed and funded early education (in the States, and everywhere else...).

America’s future early education system

by Lane Kenworthy
At some point, the United States is likely to have universal publicly-funded early education for children aged one to four. But while we led the way in establishing universal elementary and secondary schooling and in expanding access to college, on early education we lag well behind some other rich nations. We should pick up the pace.
WHY EARLY EDUCATION?
Universal early education will have two significant benefits. First, many Americans with prekindergarten children want to combine family with paid work.1But because good-quality out-of-home care can be prohibitively expensive, too many parents settle for care that is mediocre or poor.2 Others simply forgo employment.3
Denmark and Sweden offer a good model. Beginning in the 1960s, these countries introduced and then steadily expanded paid parental leave and publicly-funded childcare and preschool. Today, Danish and Swedish parents can take a paid year off work following the birth of a child. After that, parents can put the child in a public or licensed private early education center. The quality tends to be high, as early education teachers get training and pay comparable to elementary school teachers. Parents pay a fee, but the cost is capped at less than 10% of a household's income.4
We can see the impact in employment patterns. Among mothers whose youngest child is six to sixteen years old, and thus eligible for free K-12 schooling, the employment rate in the U.S. is just a few percentage points lower than in Denmark and Sweden. Among mothers with a child younger than six, it's 15 percentage points lower.5
Second, evidence increasingly suggests that good-quality universal early education helps to equalize opportunity by improving the capabilities of children from less advantaged homes.
Americans are strong believers in equality of opportunity. More than 90% of us think "our society should do what is necessary to make sure that everyone has an equal opportunity to succeed."6 But family conditions are a huge impediment. Some children have parents who read to them, instill helpful traits such as self-control and persistence, shield them from stress and physical harm, expose them to new information and learning opportunities, assist them with homework, provide connections that help them get out of trouble or into a good job, remain in a stable relationship throughout the childhood years, and so on. Other children are less fortunate.7 As a result, whereas an American born into a family in the top fifth of incomes has roughly an 80% chance of ending up in the middle fifth or higher in adulthood, an American born into the bottom fifth has only a 30% chance of reaching the middle fifth or higher.8
Schools help to offset the massive differences in capabilities caused by families. Children from poor homes tend to have much lower measurable skills than children from affluent homes at kindergarten entry. Given the huge variation in home and neighborhood circumstances, we would expect that gap to widen throughout childhood. But it doesn't; it's about the same size at the end of high school.9 This tells us that schools have an equalizing effect. Also, during summer vacations, when children are out of school, those from lower-income families tend to fall farther behind.10
If school began earlier in life, we could reduce some of the disparity that exists when children arrive for kindergarten. Indeed, some analysts conclude that the impact of schooling is larger before kindergarten than after.11
The effects of three high-quality early education programs -- the Perry Preschool Program in Michigan in the 1960s, the Abecedarian Project in North Carolina in the 1970s, and the Child-Parent Center Education Program in Chicago in the 1970s -- have been tracked into early adulthood or beyond. Each program appears to have had positive effects for low-income children that persist throughout the life course. For the Perry and Chicago Programs, gains in test scores faded away but there were long-term gains in labor market success and other outcomes. The same appears to be true for Head Start. This suggests that the key improvement is in noncognitive skills more than in cognitive ability. On the other hand, the Abecedarian Project yielded better long-term behavioral outcomes along with sustained gains in test scores. A natural experiment in Denmark also found lasting test-score gains. So early education's benefits for children from less advantaged homes may come via both cognitive and noncognitive skills.12
Skeptics point to findings of little apparent impact of existing universal preschool programs for four-year-olds in Oklahoma and Georgia. But these programs are too new to assess long-run effects.13
The Nordic countries, particularly Denmark and Sweden, have had universal early education systems in place for a generation. This may help account for why opportunity is more equal -- children's cognitive abilities, likelihood of completing high school and college, and labor market success depend less on their parents' education, income, and parenting practices -- in these countries than in others.14
In sum, good-quality universal early education will improve work-family balance and very likely will reduce inequality of opportunity.
A possible third benefit is faster economic growth. If universal early education increases employment by mothers and improves the capabilities of Americans who grow up in less advantaged homes, it may boost the economy's growth rate. But I'm much less confident about this outcome than the other two. Though the Nordic countries have had universal early education for several decades, their economies don't grow more rapidly now than they used to. Nor do they (apart from oil-rich Norway) grow faster than other affluent nations. If early education does increase economic growth, its impact probably is small enough that it's overshadowed by the myriad other determinants of national growth rates.15
WHY PUBLIC?
So the potential benefit from early education is substantial. Why does government need to step in? Can't the market handle this?
No, not well enough. A good early education system will combine three features: accessibility, affordability, and quality. For Americans able and willing to pay a lot for childcare, our current system typically delivers all three. But for those with low to moderate incomes, getting access to affordable care too often means sacrificing quality.16 A universal system with public funding and some direct public provision would change this. It would ensure good-quality care to everyone at an affordable price.
But let's break this down. Should government pay for early education? Yes, to make it affordable for all. That doesn't mean it should be free, as I'll explain in a moment, but it does mean taxpayers should bear a significant portion of the cost.
Here government already is involved. The federal government funds Head Start, some special education services, and tax breaks for childcare. Some state governments fund preschool for four-year-olds and subsidize childcare for poor families. But this is nowhere near sufficient to ensure that everyone has access to good-quality care and preschool.
Do we also need government to provide early education? Yes. That's the only way to guarantee universal access to preschool and care that's above an acceptable quality threshold. But we don't need government to be the sole provider. Denmark and Sweden allow private providers, as long as they meet quality standards. In many districts across America we allow private providers for publicly-funded K-12 schooling (charter schools). We allow private doctors and hospitals to provide medical care for Medicare and Medicaid recipients. We should do the same for early education.
What's the ideal mix? I don't know. Maybe it's 25% of kids in public early education centers, or perhaps it's 75%. This depends largely on how many private providers can combine good quality with a reasonable rate of return.
WHY UNIVERSAL?
Why should early education be universal? Why not just expand Head Start a bit?
Three reasons. First, it isn't just low-income parents who struggle to find good-quality care that's affordable. Middle-class parents do too. Second, family structure and parents' traits and behaviors are key sources of disadvantage, and they don't overlap perfectly with family income. If we target low-income households, we'll miss many children who need help. Third, development of cognitive and especially noncognitive skills is aided by peer interaction. Children from less advantaged homes gain by mixing with kids from middle-class homes, which doesn't happen in a program that exclusively serves the poor.17
WHY NOT BEGIN AT BIRTH?
If early education is so great, why not encourage parents to start right after birth? The reason is that research suggests children tend to fare best staying with a parent during the first year of life.18
So along with facilitating early education for kids aged one to four, we should make it possible for more parents to stay home with their children during the first year.19 Right now, we require that firms with 50 or more employees grant 12 weeks of unpaid leave to new parents.20 Some large firms offer paid leave, but that's entirely voluntary. Here too, the Danes and Swedes have it about right. They provide tax-funded paid parental leave for roughly one year. A portion is use-it-or-lose-it for the father; if he chooses not to take any leave, the couple loses that time. Otherwise they are free to split the leave however they like.
HOW MUCH SHOULD PARENTS PAY FOR EARLY EDUCATION?
American parents with a child younger than age five in out-of-home care currently pay, on average, about $9,000 per year for that care. Childcare expenditures amount to 40% of income for families with incomes below $18,000, and 20% for those with incomes between $18,000 and $36,000.21 That's far too much.
How much should parents pay? A sliding scale, with the user fee rising in proportion to family income and capped at around 10%, seems sensible.
Should it be free for those with low incomes? I think that would be a mistake. Early education differs from services that relatively few people opt out of, such as police protection, healthcare, and even K-12 education. Families that prefer to provide stay-at-home parental care for their young children will elect not to use it. This argues for having parents who do use it pay something -- even parents with little income. The fee should be modest, but it shouldn't be zero.
HOW MUCH WILL IT COST TAXPAYERS?
The bill to taxpayers will depend on specific details, but a rough estimate is 1% of GDP, or $160 billion, per year.
There are two ways to reach this number. First, our public spending on K-12 education is about 4% of GDP, or $600 billion.22 There are 50 million students in our public K-12 schools (the enrollment rate is 85-90%23), so public expenditures come to about $12,000 per student. There are around 16 million children aged one to four. Suppose 75% enroll in early education; that's 12 million children. If we spend $12,000 per child, the same as for K-12 schools, total spending would be around $145 billion. We'll want a better teacher-child ratio for early education, which will increase the cost a bit, though user fees will help cover this.
Second, public expenditure on early education in Denmark and Sweden is about 1.5% of GDP.24 We're likely to end up with more private provision and we have a larger per capita GDP, so 1% of our GDP might well be sufficient to create a system that approximates theirs in quality and accessibility.
Note that my estimate of the cost is far higher than that of recent proposals by the Obama administration and the Center for American Progress.25 That's because those proposals are for relatively small additions to our current system.
How much will taxes increase for individual households? If the distribution of new tax payments needed to fund early education is the same as for existing tax payments, households in the bottom fifth of incomes will pay $133 more per year, those in the lower-middle fifth $333, those in the middle fifth $666, those in the upper-middle fifth $1,266, and those in the top fifth $4,200.26 These amounts are fairly small -- an advantage of spreading the bill across the population.27
Over the long run, universal early education may pay for itself via increased employment and productivity.28 Even if it doesn't, however, it's well worth doing in order to improve work-family balance and equality of opportunity.
SO WHAT'S NOT TO LIKE?
I see seven principal objections to universal publicly-funded early education for the United States.
First, when someone suggests borrowing a policy or institution from the Nordic countries, skeptics immediately point out that these countries are very different from America. They're small, they're more ethnically and racially homogenous, and their cultures and histories are quite distinct from ours. What works there, in other words, won't necessarily work here.
That's true. But it doesn't justify blanket skepticism about borrowing. We need to consider the particulars of the policy in question. There is no reason to think a system of publicly-funded early education centers (schools) can function effectively only in a small homogenous country. France does this, even though it's a pretty large nation. Belgium does too, despite its diversity.29 And we do a reasonably good job ourselves with kindergartens and elementary schools. Education experts and ordinary Americans routinely profess dissatisfaction with our K-12 public schools. But recall the evidence I mentioned earlier: inequality in capabilities expands when children aren't in school (before kindergarten and during summers), while K-12 schools hold it at bay. American schools could be better, to be sure, but for less advantaged children they are, even in their current condition, far more helpful than the likely alternative.
A second objection is that we don't know how large the impact of early education will be in boosting the capabilities of children from less advantaged families. The expectation of a sizeable effect is compelling, and we have supportive evidence from K-12 schooling, from three high-quality early education programs, and from cross-country comparison. But that evidence is limited.30
Though this is a legitimate concern, it shouldn't dissuade us. Equalizing opportunity is such a prized goal that even a modest improvement would be valuable. And regardless of its impact on opportunity, early education will be of considerable benefit in helping parents balance work and family.
Third, some contend that more government spending and higher taxes will hurt the economy. But the relevant evidence says otherwise. Over the past century the United States has shifted from a country with a small government to one with a medium-sized government, but our long-term rate of economic growth hasn't slowed. And among the world's rich nations, those with larger governments have tended to grow just as rapidly as those with smaller governments.31
Fourth, some believe government provision of services and benefits weakens families.32 If parents have access to affordable good-quality childcare and preschool, will they be less likely to stay together or get married in the first place? That's conceivable, but the historical and comparative evidence suggests reason for skepticism. Enrollment in elementary and secondary schools grew steadily in the United States from the late 1800s until around 1960, but it was in the 1960s, after the rise in school enrollment slowed sharply, that rates of divorce and out-of-wedlock birth shot up.33 And more children grow up with both parents in Denmark, France, and Sweden, each of which has a universal early education system, than in the United States.34
Fifth, some worry about rent-seeking if a substantial amount of early education is publicly provided. Public-sector employees may be able to get above-market pay and benefits, increasing the cost to taxpayers.35 The evidence on this is mixed.36 But suppose we as a collectivity do end up paying more than we need to. The question is whether the outcome is worth it. My judgment is yes. It's the same with our military, police protection, fire fighting, medical care, K-12 schooling, and others. These services yield immense individual and social benefits, and I'm willing to bear a slightly elevated cost in order to ensure that all Americans have access to them.
A sixth objection suggests that publicly-provided services tend to be of low quality. But the evidence from our public K-12 schools offers cause for optimism. While there is lots of room for improvement, they do help to equalize opportunity. They also, of course, facilitate employment by parents. Public early education will do the same.
Finally, why not just give the money to parents and let them choose whether to use it on early education or on something else? The reason is that if early education has individual and social benefits, it makes sense to require that the money be used for that and only that. The same is true of safety (military, police), infrastructure (roads, bridges), health insurance (Medicare, Medicaid), and K-12 schooling, among others. Though paternalism is a dirty word for some, a key purpose of government is precisely to help us do things we might not choose on our own.
It's worth emphasizing that having a universal early education system doesn't mean anyone will be forced to use it. Parents who prefer to stay home with their children during the first five years will still be able to do so.
WHAT'S IN IT FOR REPUBLICANS?
In 2012, 20 million Americans with incomes below $50,000 voted Republican in the presidential election. Many in this group who have young children can't afford good-quality out-of-home care. These parents and their kids would benefit from universal early education. The same is true for some of the 20 million Republican voters with incomes between $50,000 and $100,000.37 Republican leaders who want to improve their constituents' well-being ought to be interested in early education.
Moreover, many of these Americans would embrace publicly-funded early education, at least after the fact. Yes, a significant share of them dislike the idea of big government, but they nevertheless like a lot of the public insurance and public services that our government provides.38 Many of them happily send their children off to public elementary schools, middle schools, and high schools every day. They would do the same with early education. In Oklahoma, one of the reddest of red states, the enrollment rate in the public preschool program for four-year-olds is 74%.39
PATIENCE IS A VIRTUE, BUT WHY WAIT?
America is a long way from universal early education, and the difficult part is the politics. But that's often the case. Consider healthcare. We began by creating the Veteran's Administration after the Civil War. Tax breaks for employer contributions to private health insurance came after World War II. Medicare and Medicaid were created in the 1960s. Medicaid coverage was expanded in the 1980s and 1990s, and Medicare in the 2000s. The Affordable Care Act arrived in 2010, and even when it is fully implemented we'll still fall short of universal access and affordable cost. Advances in our public insurance and public services tend to come incrementally, and early education may be no exception.
But that doesn't mean it's best to proceed slowly. The case for universal good-quality publicly-funded early education is strong. For America's parents and children, sooner would be better than later.

Notes
1. Americans used to worry about mothers of young children working outside the home. In the late 1970s, 68% believed "a preschool child is likely to suffer if his or her mother works." But by 2012, the share had shrunk to 35% (General Social Survey, variable fepresch). Indeed, nowadays support for paid work among mothers of young kids spans the political spectrum. Many conservatives favor strict time limits on receipt of government benefits in order to encourage mothers' employment, and gender egalitarians point out that four or five years out of the work force (more if there is a second or third child) puts women at a severe disadvantage for later employment and earnings. See Ron Haskins,Work Over Welfare, Brookings Institution Press, 2007; Janet C. Gornick, Marcia K. Meyers, et al, Gender Equality, Verso, 2009.
2. Deborah Lowe Vandell and Barbara Wolfe, "Child Care Quality: Does It Matter and Does It Need to Be Improved?" Special Report 78, Institute for Research on Poverty, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 2000; Jane Waldfogel, What Children Need, Harvard University Press, 2006; W. Steven Barnett et al, The State of Preschool 2012, National Institute for Early Education Research; Jonathan Cohn, "The Hell of American Day Care," The New Republic, 2013.
3. The labor force participation rate of mothers with children younger than six is just 65%. Bureau of Labor Statistics, "Employment Characteristics of Families -- 2012," using Current Population Survey data.
4. OECD, Starting Strong II: Early Childhood Education and Care, 2006; OECD,Doing Better for Families, 2011; Miriam Nordfors, "Sweden Solves Two Problems at Once," New York Times: Room for Debate, 2013.
5. OECD, Doing Better for Families, figure 1.9. There is additional U.S.-specific evidence suggesting the employment rate among mothers with young children would be higher if good-quality early education were more accessible; see, for instance, Janice Compton and Robert A. Pollak, "Family Proximity, Childcare, and Women's Labor Force Attachment," Working Paper 17678, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2011. Timothy Bartik concludes that the employment benefits of early education are not just in the quantity of jobs but also their quality. See Bartik, Investing in Kids: Early Childhood Programs and Local Economic Development, W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, 2011.
6. Pew Research Center, 1987-2012.
7. Greg J. Duncan and Richard J. Murnane, eds., Whither Opportunity? Rising Inequality, Schools, and Children's Life Chances, Russell Sage Foundation and Spencer Foundation, 2011; Annette Lareau, Unequal Childhoods, 2nd edition, University of California Press, 2011.
8. Economic Mobility Project, "Pursuing the American Dream: Economic Mobility Across Generations," Pew Charitable Trusts, 2012. These numbers are for Americans born between the mid-1960s and the mid-1980s. In a society with perfectly equal opportunity, every person would have a 20% chance of landing on each of the five rungs of the income ladder and a 60% chance of landing on the middle rung or a higher one.
9. James J. Heckman, "Schools, Skills, and Synapses," Working Paper 14064, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2008; Sean F. Reardon, "The Widening Academic-Achievement Gap Between the Rich and the Poor: New Evidence and Possible Explanations," in Whither Opportunity?, figure 5.5; John Ermisch, Markus Jäntti, and Timothy Smeeding, eds., From Parents to Children: The Intergenerational Transmission of Advantage, Russell Sage Foundation, 2012, pp. 465-468.
10. Douglas B. Downey, Paul T. von Hippel, and Beckett A. Broh, "Are Schools the Great Equalizer? Cognitive Inequality during the Summer Months and the School Year," American Sociological Review, 2004; Karl L. Alexander, Doris R. Entwisle, and Linda Steffel Olson, "Lasting Consequences of the Summer Learning Gap," American Sociological Review, 2007. For discussion of additional findings from natural experiments in which children go without schooling, see Richard E. Nisbett, Intelligence and How to Get It, W.W. Norton, 2009, ch. 3.
11. Jeanne Brooks-Gunn, "What We Can Expect from Early Childhood Intervention Programs," Society for Research in Child Development, 2003; Heckman, "Schools, Skills, and Synapses"; Douglas Almond and Janet Currie,"Human Capital Development Before Age Five," Working Paper 15827, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2010.
12. Heckman, "Schools, Skills, and Synapses"; David Deming, "Early Childhood Intervention and Life-Cycle Skill Development: Evidence from Head Start,"American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2009; Arthur J. Reynolds et al, "Age 26 Cost-Benefit Analysis of the Child-Parent Center Early Education Program," Child Development, 2011; Gøsta Esping-Andersen, Irwin Garfinkel, Wen-Jui Han, Katherine Magnuson, Sander Wagner, and Jane Waldfogel, "Child Care and School Performance in Denmark and the United States," Children and Youth Services Review, 2012; Greg J. Duncan and Katherine Magnuson,"Investing in Preschool Programs," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2013.
13. Duncan and Magnuson, "Investing in Preschool Programs." See also W. Steven Barnett, "Getting the Facts Right on Pre-K," National Institute for Early Education Research, 2013.
14. Tarjei Havnes and Magne Mogstad, "Is Universal Child Care Leveling the Playing Field?," IZA Discussion Paper 4978, 2010; Smeeding, Erickson, and Jäntti, eds., From Parents to Children; Gøsta Esping-Andersen, The Incomplete Revolution, Polity, 2009, ch. 4.
15. A fourth potential benefit is higher fertility. Families that know having a child won't severely interrupt the work career of either the father or mother are more likely to have the number of children they desire. If we look across Europe, countries with universal early education tend to have higher fertility rates; see Francis G. Castles, "The World Turned Upside Down: Below Replacement Fertility, Changing Preferences, and Family-Friendly Public Policy in 21 OECD Countries," Journal of European Public Policy, 2003; OECD, Doing Better for Families, ch. 3; Esping-Andersen, The Incomplete Revolution. But this doesn't seem to be a significant barrier to fertility in the United States.
16. See note 2.
17. Eric A. Hanushek, John F. Kain, Jacob M. Markman, and Steven G. Rivkin,"Does Peer Ability Affect Student Achievement?" Working Paper 8502, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2001; Heckman, "Schools, Skills, and Synapses"; Robert Bauchmüller, Mette Gørtz and Astrid Würtz Rasmussen,"Long-Run Benefits from Universal High-Quality Preschooling," AKF Working Paper, 2011; Barnett, "Getting the Facts Right on Pre-K."
18. Waldfogel, What Children Need, ch. 2; Jeanne Brooks-Gunn, Wen-Jui Han, and Jane Waldfogel, "First-Year Maternal Employment and Child Development in the First Seven Years," Monographs of the Society for Research in Child Development, 2010; Maria del Carmen Huerta et al, "Early Maternal Employment and Child Development in Five OECD Countries," OECD Social, Employment, and Migration Working Paper 118, 2011.
19. The apparent impact of California's paid leave program is encouraging. See Maya Rossin-Slater, Christopher J. Ruhm, and Jane Waldfogel, "The Effects of California's Paid Family Leave Program on Mothers' Leave-Taking and Subsequent Labor Market Outcomes," Journal of Public Policy Analysis and Management, 2013.
20. The 1993 Family and Medical Leave Act.
21. Lynda Laughlin, "Who's Minding the Kids? Child Care Arrangements: Spring 2011," U.S. Census Bureau, 2013, table 6, using data from the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP). See also Ajay Chaudry et al, "Child Care Choices of Low-Income Working Families," Urban Institute, 2011; ChildCare Aware of America, "Parents and the High Cost of Child Care," 2012.
22. OECD, Education at a Glance 2012, table B2.3.
23. The other 10-15% are in private schools, home school, or dropped out.
24. OECD, Doing Better for Families, figure 1.11.
25. Obama Administration 2014 Budget Proposal; Cynthia G. Brown, Donna Cooper, Juliana Herman, Melissa Lazarín, Michael Linden, Sasha Post, and Neera Tanden, "Investing in Our Children: A Plan to Expand Access to Preschool and Child Care," Center for American Progress, 2013.
26. According to Citizens for Tax Justice ("America's Tax System Is Not as Progressive as You Think," 2011), if we take all types of taxes into account -- federal, state, and local (personal and corporate income, payroll, property, sales, excise, estate, etc.) -- households in the bottom fifth of incomes pay about 2% of the taxes, those in the lower-middle fifth pay 5%, those in the middle fifth pay 10%, those in the upper-middle fifth pay 19%, and those in the top fifth pay 63%. Each fifth has about 24 million households. The amount paid by households in the bottom fifth is calculated as $160 billion (the total tax revenue needed) multiplied by .02 (this group will account for 2% of the revenues) divided by 24 million (the number of households in this group) = $133. The calculation is analogous for the other four groups.
27. The $4,200 tab for those in the top fifth might seem large, but that's the average for this group. We can break this down further. Those between the 80th and 90th percentiles would pay $2,000 more per year, those between the 90th and 95th percentiles $2,933, those between the 95th and 99th percentiles $5,333, and those in the top 1 percent (average income above $1 million) $29,333.
28. Heckman, "Schools, Skills, and Synapses"; Esping-Andersen, The Incomplete Revolution.
29. Barbara R. Bergmann, Saving Our Children from Poverty: What the United States Can Learn from France, Russell Sage Foundation, 1996; Janet C. Gornick and Marcia K. Meyers, Families That Work, Russell Sage Foundation, 2003; OECD, Doing Better for Families; Claire Lundberg, "Maybe Working MomsCan Have It All -- in France," Slate, 2012.
30. Charles Murray, "Response to Heckman: Weighing the Evidence," Boston Review, 2012; Grover J. "Russ" Whitehurst, "Can We Be Hard-Headed About Preschool? A Look at Universal and Targeted Pre-K," Brookings Institution, 2013; Will Wilkinson, "Does Subsidized Preschool Pay Off?" The Economist: Democracy in America, 2013.
31. Lane Kenworthy, Social Democratic America, Oxford University Press, forthcoming 2014.
32. Mary Eberstadt, "The Post-Welfare State Family," The Weekly Standard, 2013.
33. Claudia Goldin and Lawrence F. Katz, The Race between Education and Technology, Harvard University Press, 2008, figure 6.1; Census Bureau; National Center for Health Statistics.
34. OECD, "SF1.3: Living Arrangements of Children," OECD Family Database.
35. Reihan Salam, "The House Budget Committee on the Inequality Landscape,"National Review Online: The Agenda, 2011.
36. Controlling for education and other relevant factors, federal government employees have higher compensation (wages and benefits) than their private-sector counterparts but state and local government employees don't. Jeffrey Keefe, "Debunking the Myth of the Overcompensated Public Employee: The Evidence," Economic Policy Institute, 2010; Philipp Bewerunge and Harvey S. Rosen, "Wages, Pensions, and Public-Private Sector Compensation Differentials," Working Paper 227, Griswold Center for Economic Policy Studies, 2012; Congressional Budget Office, "Comparing the Compensation of Federal and Private-Sector Employees," 2012.
37. 127 million Americans voted. According to exit polls, 41% had incomes below $50,000, and 39% of them voted Republican; 31% had incomes between $50,000 and $100,000, with 52% of them voting Republican.
38. Lane Kenworthy, "What Do Americans Want?" 2013.
39. Barnett et al, The State of Preschool 2012, table 2.
Lane Kenworthy | May 19, 2013 at 8:50 pm | Categories: EducationLiving standards,OpportunitySocial policy | URL: http://wp.me/p8wob-25l
Comment   See all comments
Unsubscribe or change your email settings at Manage Subscriptions.
Trouble clicking? Copy and paste this URL into your browser:
http://lanekenworthy.net/2013/05/19/americas-future-early-education-system-2/

British humour

I've been traveling a lot recently, including in England (Leicester), where these "rules and regulations" were posted in the hotel lobby. And, non, I was not spending time in the Fawlty Towers ;-)